Reconstruction in the immediate aftermath of war
a comparative study of Europe, 1945-50
introduction introduction  
news news  
balzan fdt. balzan fdt.  
people people  
research research  
events 
1st workshop    
2nd workshop    
3rd workshop    
4th workshop 
programme    
report   
conference    
.

Waqar Zaidi, Planning, Production and Reconstruction in Postwar Europe: Fourth BAlzan Workshop, Birkbeck College, London, 26 June 2007

This was the fourth and final workshop of the Balzan Project on the history of European reconstruction after World War Two. The previous workshops had compared reconstruction in Western and Eastern Europe and reconstruction after World War One with reconstruction after World War Two, and had focused on the movement of populations and their relief and rehabilitation.1 This one focused on planning, particularly industrial, agricultural and urban planning, within the context of immediate postwar European reconstruction. Situated at the fruitful intersection between cultural and economic history, the papers permitted investigation of a wide range of themes, including clashing ideologies, epistemic communities and continuities from the Third Reich. Comments and discussions revealed that crucial areas still need to be better understood in relation to postwar planning, including the national arms industries, the relationship to the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP), and, of course, ideological divides between East and West.

John R. Gillingham (University of Missouri, St Louis) kicked off with a paper addressing the foundations of postwar German economic growth. Many of the histories of postwar Germany have argued or assumed, he noted, that state planning laid the foundations of postwar German economic growth ? a prominent example being Barry Eichengreen?s argument that the revival of central wage-bargaining was central to postwar German economic growth. Gillingham, in his paper ?Planning Europe after 1945: the German Case?, argued that, actually, there was no central coherent planning within West Germany of any significant relevance to its future economic growth ? particularly in comparison to France and Britain. The planning for postwar reconstruction that had been carried out during World War Two was wrecked by contrary Allied planning (for example the Morgenthau plan) as well as the Potsdam settlement. Confusion and conflict in Allied policy delayed recovery and limited early postwar decision-making to the short term.

Some recovery did take place, however, because in actuality Germany was richer and more capable than is generally supposed. Many Nazi-era economic controls remained in place during the early postwar period, and planning became a matter of resolving industrial bottle-necks (for example in transport) and of recreating capitalist institutions. Allied policy-making was nevertheless frustrated for many years, and faltering reconstruction was eventually saved through the intervention of German policy-makers such as Ludwig Erhard who, having backgrounds outside of the traditional communities of planners and policy-makers, used pre-existing and recently revised institutions to implement pragmatic and ?quick-fix? policies ? most prominently the currency devaluation of 1948. Wage-gains were deferred in favour of reinvestment in the early fifties, leading to the economic strengthening of Germany and creation of a ?German model? which influenced market regulation in the rest of Western Europe. This German recovery, concluded Gillingham, was not predicated on Keynesianism or any other tradition of economic thought dating to the interwar period, and consequently should not be seen as a triumph of ?planning?.

Katherine Lebow (University of Virginia) presented a study of planning for and within the city of Nowa Huta, Poland?s ?first socialist city? and possibly the most visible and celebrated of such cities built in the Eastern bloc countries after World War Two. Her paper ?Three Ironies of Stalinist Planning? revealed a history of planning very much at odds with what we might expect from this most Stalinist of cities. Firstly, contrary to common perceptions, plans for the creation of Nowa Huta drew deeply on indigenous pre-Stalinist thinking ? planning for the creation of new steel-works and associated cities was already well advanced prior to the advent of the one-party Communist state in Poland. Secondly, contrary to the characterization of socialism by its critics, there was no linear connection between ?blueprint? and action during the creation of Nowa Huta ? concrete plans were often made to achieve fuzzy goals, and the final construction was often wildly different from initial conceptualization. Lastly, Lebow noted that the centralized nature of planning for Nowa Huta encouraged demands for grass-roots participation. She presented a case-study from early 1957, when a citizens? committee in the city was given permission to build a church and was allotted a prime parcel of land. The reversal of this decision in 1958, couched in the language of planning and resource allocation, caused significant and violent clashes between protestors and security forces ? dubbed the ?Battle for the Cross?. Her concluding remarks stressed the poverty of theses which characterized authoritarian regimes as being ideologically committed to forcing reality to fit preconceived plans.

Mark Mazower (University of Columbia), commenting on Gillingham?s paper, noted that it was really about the absence of planning, a case-study of prosperity occurring once planning had been jettisoned. Gillingham?s thesis, noted Mazower, was predicated on characterizing German policy- makers such as Erhard as outsiders ? outside, that is, of epistemic communities which carried out postwar planning during World War Two. But, asked Mazower, is it possible that Third Reich planners in the early 1940s produced plans which looked similar to the eventual postwar reality ? that perhaps Erhard was actually part of a Third Reich planning epistemic community? Gillingham?s paper suggested that Germany broke with a tradition of national autarchy dating back to the thirties only in the postwar period; Mazower posed instead the possibility that Germany had already largely broken with this tradition and replaced it with European autarchy during World War Two ? much earlier than Gillingham suggested.

Mazower noted that Lebow?s paper raised a significant number of questions regarding the nature of planning in Poland and across Eastern Europe, and seemed to address a clash between bourgeois and Stalinist planning policy. What was the relationship, he wondered, between German wartime planning and postwar planning in Poland? Is it possible that Polish postwar planning was consciously directed against wartime German planning? Was planning more important as rhetoric in the postwar Stalinist era, rather than as an attempt to create a material existence? More broadly, he wondered if there was a single distinctive European story about planning, or whether European postwar history really is one of wildly different types of planning. Further comments from the floor generally centred on the need to specify and distinguish between different types and levels of planning in order to understand their ideological motivation.

To these thoughts from Mazower, and questions from the floor, Gillingham responded that German wartime planning was fundamentally different from postwar planning. Third Reich planning presupposed and was founded upon a German victory over Europe; it depended much less on the state, and much more on organized business. This type of planning did carry over to the postwar period in certain aspects, however: for example through consumer-industry financing of production industries. Lebow, in response to the suggestion that there might be a clash of planning ideologies at play in the history of Nowa Huta, noted that Polish wartime and early postwar planning was not an exercise in ideology. New industrial towns met the very real and pressing need for housing, and many of the early postwar planners in Poland were young professionals reacting to the opportunities of reconstruction and pursuing their own professional and social goals.

Jacek Kochanowicz (Warsaw University) began the second half of the workshop with his paper on early postwar economic planning in Poland: ?A Dual Reconstruction: Notes on the Polish Recovery and the Beginnings of Systemic Change, 1944?49?. He argued that there were two coexisting approaches, one Communist and the other Social Democratic, to high-level planning and economic reconstruction between 1944 and 1949. Both were embodied in different distinct institutions: the Centralny Urza_d Planowania (Central Planning Office ? ?CUP?) under the leadership of Czeslaw Bobrowski, incorporated the latter, and the Ministry of Industry and the Economic Committee of the Council of Ministers, headed by the Stalinist economist Hilary Minc, the former.

The Ministry of Industry began formulating quarterly plans in April 1946, followed quickly by yearly investment and coal-extraction targets as well as distribution lists for crucial industrial resources such as coal, steel and timber. The Ministry used the pre-existing hierarchical structure of state industry to set mandatory production targets for, and allocate resources to, state industries and enterprises in a manner similar to the Soviet model. The CUP, meanwhile, was formed in 1945 to co- ordinate and plan beyond industry and for the whole economy. The CUP allocated state funds to state and non-state organizations, and also set various types of targets for state and non-state enterprises. Its planning encompassed the whole economy, and assumed and allowed for a significant private sector. The social-democratic approach embodied by the CUP was eventually unable to withstand the onslaught of growing Communist influence and Stalinization. The CUP was dissolved in the beginning of 1949 amongst charges of ineptitude, ?bourgeois? methods of national- income accounting and insufficient ?Marxist foundations?, and new Stalinist state institutions were created leading to the setting up of a full-scale Soviet-style command economy.

Kiran Patel (Humboldt University), speaking on ?The Long Shadow of the Reich: Agricultural Planning in Postwar West Germany?, turned his attention to what he considered to be the central paradox at the heart of West German agricultural planning after the war. Postwar German agricultural planning, from a strictly economic viewpoint, was not particularly successful. Yet, argued Patel, it was exactly these shortcomings from the viewpoint of economic planning which made agricultural policy a success when viewed as social policy. In order to understand how and why this occurred, he argued, it is crucial to realize that from the days of the Third Reich the character of postwar Germanagricultural policy remained unchanged in some crucial ways ? most importantly, it retained its statist character and, in the forties, its consumer orientation. Contradictions in Allied crisis management, lack of co-ordination and a restrictive industrial policy made agrarian policy unsuccessful between the Potsdam conference and 1948. From 1948 to 1949, despite two bumper crops, agricultural planning impeded the rise of production as much as it supported it. Although alternative paths were possible, the newly formed Federal Republic, founded in 1949, continued this protectionist course and, crucially, introduced market regulation for all important agricultural commodities ? in doing so it formally reintroduced the central elements of state planning so prevalent in the 1930s. The advent of this protectionist agricultural policy did however herald a shift away from an earlier consumer orientation and towards a producer-orientated strategy with a clear social objective: the closing of the income gap between the agricultural population and those employed in other sectors. The advent of the Federal Agricultural Law (Bundeslandwirtschaftsgesetz) in 1955, thanks to the initiative of the extremely powerful German Farmers? Union (Deutscher Bauernverband), along with the subsequent ?Green Plan? and ?Green Reports?, ensured that not just big farmers but smaller ones benefited too. This German agricultural policy was, as social policy, a success, argued Patel: the agricultural sector had immense symbolic importance to the country and support for it boosted the legitimacy of the state.

Alan Milward (official historian at the Cabinet Office), in presenting his thoughts on the final two papers and the workshop as a whole, focused on the relationship between the state and planning. Although planning, he suggested, was not as important an activity as it is generally made out to be, there existed nevertheless the issue of why states carried out social planning in the postwar period. The persistence of ?social states? ? states characterized by social planning ? he suggested, needed further investigation. An immediate need for housing, as well as culture, might well form part of the explanation for their existence. The reason for a shift from housing to higher levels of planning also needs to be understood, and may lie, he suggested, with the peculiar needs of the armaments industries for modern war: their co-ordination, planning and centralization. He suggested that an investigation of the needs of highly-geared modern warfare in World War Two, for example Blitzkrieg, could explain the growth in trade and exports and so also state planning in the wartime and postwar period.

In the ensuing discussion comparisons were made between Hungarian and Polish planning ? it was noted that the split between the two opposing planning approaches occurred much later in the Hungarian case. CAP was discussed, and comparisons were also made between postwar British and German agricultural policies. It was noted however that comparative studies of Eastern and Western European agriculturalpolicy were lacking and were needed to further our understanding of postwar European planning.The importance of understanding postwar reconstruction to a fuller grasp of Europe in the postwar period has long been recognized. The Balzan workshop programme has illuminated some aspects of this reconstruction, and has highlighted the need for further research into others. It has, moreover, suggested ways in which reconstruction can serve as a site for the exploration of much wider issues of import to the history of Europe: issues of policy and ideology, of social change and material culture. It has given us a sense of just how little we know about reconstruction, and how knowing more may change our picture of Europe today. Waqar Zaidi Imperial College London.


(C) Jessica Reinisch, 2010-06-25. All rights reserved.